MN Statute 147E registers naturopathic doctors effective July 2009 and mandates a work group to recommend measures to ensure MN Statute 146A effectively protects unlicensed healers and, also, to study naturopathic regulation laws in other states. All opinions welcome. In the spirit of the work group, where the unregulated and regulated healers concerns will find an equitable solution, we hope this blog will engender a friendly and meaningful conversation.

Wednesday, May 21, 2008

1962 Milton Friedman Essay

Medical Licensure
by Milton Friedman

The medical profession is one in which practice of the profession has for a long time been restricted to people with licenses. Offhand, the question, "Ought we to let incompetent physicians practice?" seems to admit of only a negative answer. But I want to urge that second thought may give pause.

In the first place, licensure is the key to the control that the medical profession can exercise over the number of physicians. To understand why this is so requires some discussion of the structure of the medical profession. The American Medical Association is perhaps the strongest trade union in the United States. The essence of the power of a trade union is its power to restrict the number who may engage in a particular occupation. This restriction may be exercised indirectly by being able to enforce a wage rate higher than would otherwise prevail. If such a wage rate can be enforced, it will reduce the number of people who can get jobs and thus indirectly the number of people pursuing the occupation. This technique of restriction has disadvantages. There is always a dissatisfied fringe of people who are trying to get into the occupation. A trade union is much better off it can limit directly the number of people who enter the occupation-who ever try to get jobs in it. The disgruntled and dissatisfied are excluded at the outset, and the union does not have to worry about them.

The American Medical Association is in this position. It is a trade union that can limit the number of people who can enter. How can it do this? The essential control is at the stage of admission to medical school. The Council on Medical Education and Hospitals of the American Medical Association approves medical schools. In order for a medical school to get and stay on its list of approved schools it has to meet the standards of the Council. The power of the Council has been demonstrated at various times when there has been pressure to reduce numbers. For example, in the 1930's during the depression, the Council on Medical Education and Hospitals wrote a letter to the various medical schools saying the medical schools were admitting more students than could be given the proper kind of training. In the next year or two, every school reduced the number it was admitting, giving very strong presumptive evidence that the recommendation had some effect. . . .

Control over admission to medical school and later licensure enables the profession to limit entry in two ways. The obvious one is simply by turning down many applicants. The less obvious, but probably far more important one, is by establishing standards for admission and licensure that make entry so difficult as to discourage young people from ever trying to get admission. . . .

In the first place, does [licensure] really raise standards of competence? It is by no means clear that it does raise the standards of competence in the actual practice of the profession for several reasons. In the first place, whenever you establish a block to entry into any field, you establish an incentive to find ways of getting around it, and of course medicine is no exception. The rise of the professions of osteopathy and of chiropractic is not unrelated to the restriction of entry into medicine. On the contrary, each of these represented, to some extent, an attempt to find a way around restriction of entry. Each of these, in turn, is proceeding to get itself licensed, and to impose restrictions. The effect is to create different levels and kinds of practice, to distinguish between what is called medical practice and substitutes such as osteopathy, chiropractic, faith healing and so on. These alternatives may well be of lower quality than medical practice would have been without the restrictions on entry into medicine.

More generally, if the number of physicians is less than it otherwise would be, and if they are fully occupied, as they generally are, this means that there is a smaller total of medical practice by trained physicians-fewer medical man-hours of practice, as it were. The alternative is untrained practice by somebody; it may and in part must be by people who have no professional qualifications at all. Moreover, the situation is much more extreme. If "medical practice" is to be limited to licensed practitioners, it is necessary to define what medical practice is, and featherbedding is not something that is restricted to the railroads. Under the interpretation of the statutes forbidding unauthorized practice of medicine, many things are restricted to licensed physicians that could perfectly well be done by technicians, and other skilled people who do not have a Cadillac medical training. I am not enough of a technician to list the examples at all fully. I only know that those who have looked into the question say that the tendency is to include in "medical practice" a wider and wider range of activities that might well be done by others. The result is to reduce drastically the amount of medical care. The relevant average quality of medical care, if one can at all conceive of the concept, cannot be obtained by simply averaging the quality of care that is given; that would be like judging the effectiveness of a medical treatment by considering only the survivors; one must also allow for the fact that the restrictions reduce the amount of care. The result may well be that the average level of competence in a meaningful sense has been reduced by the restrictions.

Even these comments do not go far enough, because they consider the situation at a point in time and do not allow for changes over time. Advances in any science or field often result from the work of one out of a large number of crackpots and quacks and people who have no standing in the profession. In the medical profession, under present circumstances, it is very difficult to engage in research or experimentation unless you are a member of the profession. If you are a member of the profession and want to stay in good standing in the profession, you are seriously limited in the kind of experimentation you can do. A "faith healer" may be just a quack who is imposing himself on credulous patients, but maybe one in a thousand or in many thousands will produce an important improvement in medicine. There are many different routes to knowledge and learning and the effect to restricting the practice of what is called medicine and defining it as we tend to do to a particular group, who in the main have to conform to the prevailing orthodoxy, is certain to reduce the amount of experimentation that goes on and hence to reduce the rate of growth of knowledge in the area. What is true for the content of medicine is true also for its organization, as has already been suggested. I shall expand further on this point below.

There is still another way in which licensure, and the associated monopoly in the practice of medicine, tend to render standards of practice low. I have already suggested that it renders the average quality of practice low by reducing the number of physicians, by reducing the aggregate number of hours available from trained physicians for more rather than less important tasks, and by reducing the incentive for research and development. It renders it low also by making it much more difficult for private individuals to collect from physicians for malpractice. One of the protections of the individual citizen against incompetence is protection against fraud and the ability to bring suit in the court against malpractice. Some suits are brought, and physicians complain a great deal about how much they have to pay for malpractice insurance. Yet suits for malpractice are fewer and less successful than they would be were it not for the watchful eye of the medical association. It is not easy to get a physician to testify against a fellow physician when he faces the sanction of being denied the right to practice in an "approved" hospital. The testimony generally has to come from members of panels set up by medical associations themselves, always, of course, in the alleged interest of the patients.

When these effects are taken into account, I am myself persuaded that licensure has reduced both the quantity and quality of medical practice; that is has reduced the opportunities available to people who would like to be physicians, forcing them to pursue occupations they regard as less attractive; that it has forced the public to pay more for less satisfactory medical service, and that it has retarded technological development both in medicine itself and in the organization of medical practice. I conclude that licensure should be eliminated as a requirement for the practice of medicine.

When all this is said, many a reader, I suspect, like many a person with whom I have discussed these issues, will say, "But still, how else would I get any evidence on the quality of a physician. Granted all that you say about costs, is not licensure the only way of providing the public with some assurance of at least minimum quality?" The answer is partly that people do not now choose physicians by picking names at random from a list of licensed physicians; partly, that a man's ability to pass an examination twenty or thirty years earlier is hardly assurance of quality now; hence, licensure is not now the main or even a major source of assurance of at least minimum quality. But the major answer is very different. It is that the question itself reveals the tyranny of the status quo and the poverty of our imagination in fields in which we are laymen, and even in those in which we have some competence, by comparison with the fertility of the market. . . .

The impossibility of any individual or small group conceiving of all the possibilities, let alone evaluating their merits, is the great argument against central governmental planning and against arrangements such as professional monopolies that limit the possibilities of experimentation. On the other side, the great argument for the market is its tolerance of diversity; its ability to utilize a wide range of special knowledge and capacity. It renders special groups impotent to prevent experimentation and permits the customers and not the producers to decide what will serve the customers best.

Professor Friedman, the winner of the 1976 Nobel Prize in Economic Science, is Senior Research Fellow at the Hoover Institution. This is an excerpt from his book Capitalism and Freedom , published in 1962 by The University of Chicago Press. © 1962 by The University of Chicago Press. Reprinted by

10 comments:

Anonymous said...

Friedman writes about the AMA medical monopoly.
Naturopathic doctor regulation would serve as an example of decreasing the yoke of such monopoly.
The opponents representing bogus diploma mills attack ND regulation
using Friedman's libertarian language.
The reality is that these diploma mills produce credentials designed to fool the public into believing that they are dealing with someone who has rigorous education and training, as provided by accredited medical schools.
Until recently the fake credential groups marketed 'Certified Naturopathic Physician' and still market 'Registered Naturopathic Doctor'.

Anonymous said...

Not regulating naturopathic doctors infringes on the public health freedom by keeping qualifed practitioners out of the market.
Compare Minnesota and Oregon.
Minnesota, unregulated, 5.1 mil population and 28 NDs.
Oregon, regulated, 3.7 mil population and 900 NDs.

Wolfgang said...

Milton Friedman?

The same Milton Friedman who helped Pinochet plan and execute a military coup in Chile resulting in death of 1000's by secret police and the destruction of their economy?

That Milton Friedman?

Thanks. I'll pass.

But Sever Yanin made a good point. Compare the states where there is regulation and where there isn't.

Wolfgang said...

Snort.

It revs me up when someone mentions the "great god" of right leaning among us, Uncle Miltie.

Here are some thoughts on the man - he was a failure in every conceivable way except the increase of the size of government.

This is from the Guardian Newspaper which has more reporters covering US politics and economics that any other news source on the planet.

Milton Friedman, who has died aged 94, was not the most important economist of the post-war era - that title belongs to the brilliant Paul Samuelson - but he was certainly the most controversial. Yet despite his views being championed by so many politicians on the right, it may come as a surprise that Friedman's career as a policymaker largely ended in failure.

Given his status as a long-standing hate figure, the assumption by many of the left is that his agenda was cemented into place during the Reagan and Thatcher administrations in the early 1980s, especially Friedman's well-known view that inflation is solely influenced by changes in the money supply. But very few of Friedman's most cherished proposals were ever put in to practice. Of those that where - such as monetarism - almost all turned into failure.

The great irony for Friedman's fans is that the one piece of public policy he was responsible for that was widely and internationally adopted was one that greatly increased the ability of central governments to collect taxes - a policy he later repudiated in disgust.

Obituaries of Friedman will doubtlessly sing of his successes. But close examination will show them to be few, and none unalloyed. For all his high public profile - thanks to his regular column in Newsweek and series on US television, Free To Choose, which made him into something of a star - today no mainstream academic economist is a monetarist and Friedman left no lasting school of academic heirs. Even the "Chicago school" at the University of Chicago has waned in influence, eclipsed by the mighty MIT army of economists that followed Samuelson.

Of course Friedman is greatly respected for his theoretical work as an economist, especially on his analysis of the role of money, the importance of inflation expectations in wages and employment, and perhaps his most lasting contribution (it could be argued), the permanent income hypothesis, which suggests that households take a longer view of anticipating their past and future income than previously thought. His award of a Nobel prize in economics was richly deserved - even if he was churlish in accepting it (he said after winning: "I would not want a professional judgment of my scientific work to be those seven people who selected me for the award").

In terms of the policies he inspired or influenced, however, the report card is not so glowing. His great claim, the idea that "inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon" may have set off the Monetarist versus Keynesian "econ-wars" of the late 1970s and 1980s. But Friedman's ideas of directly targeting the money supply were tried and rejected as a failure, in both the UK and the US, and Friedman himself backed away from his dogmatic earlier positions. Today, no major central bank directly targets money supply data in setting monetary policy - instead they are far more pragmatic. Even Friedman's great admirer Alan Greenspan never tied himself to the monetarist mast, preferring to keep his options open.

Friedman also railed long and hard for school vouchers to be adopted, to little avail, and his libertarian leanings provoked him to call for recreational drugs and prostitution to be legalised. He lobbied against environmental protection and regulations of all kinds, the vast majority of which were happily ignored by his friends and enemies. Even the economic reforms in Pinochet's Chile he is said to have inspired have run into trouble.

Friedman's first big role as a policy advisor came in 1964 to Barry Goldwater - the least successful Republican presidential candidate in the last 100 years. His next gig was for Richard Nixon - an unsuccessful president in a different way - although Nixon ignored him when it mattered, except when he could use Friedman as cover for politically difficult decisions, such as ending compulsory military service.

And Friedman's one success? In 1942, during world war two, Friedman actually went to work for the US government. While there he helped design the payroll tax that in Britain is known as PAYE, Pay As You Earn, and in the US as withholding tax, the system that allows the government to administer the taking of income tax directly from salaries and pay packets. Unlike everything else he argued for, withholding tax was withstood the test of time and is in use all around the world. It was the best thing that Keynesian-style government could ever have wished for, and Friedman bitterly regretted it. In his memoirs he wrote:

"It never occurred to me at the time that I was helping to develop machinery that would make possible a government that I would come to criticize severely as too large, too intrusive, too destructive of freedom. Yet, that is precisely what I was doing. [My wife] Rose has repeatedly chided me over the years about the role that I played in making possible the current overgrown government we both criticize so strongly."

Rest in peace Milton Friedman, big government's best friend.

Anonymous said...

Hey, W.
You do get revved up.
I cannot believe anyone would not agree that the junta takeover in Chile was a blessing and that Sal Allende was asking for trouble.
Be that as it may, the opponents of registration quote Milt, see to bhttp://www.whccamp.hhs.gov/.
Since Friedman is so quoted, is it better to examine his arguments, or to dismiss him as a right-wing wacko Nobel laureate?

Anonymous said...

Well, if the idea of licensing md's by AMA was to keep the number of MD's down, it failed to account for one large source of doctors. Foreign trained doctors make up the bulk of the resident physicians in some programs. The only thing asked of them now, is to pass the standardized exams. Therefore the main task of AMA is quality control, rather than quantity control. Therefore, naturopathic licensing will most likely have the same effect.

Wolfgang said...

Jack K,

You said "I cannot believe anyone would not agree that the junta takeover in Chile was a blessing and that Sal Allende was asking for trouble."

So by your own words you believe that democratically elected governments should be overthrown by military coup funded by foreign governments.

So how would you feel about that happening to the US, perhaps funded by China, or the Saudi's?

And yes, the reason I dismiss Friedman is precisely because of his policies. The few times they have been used they have been a disaster for everyone involved except the inevitable dictatorial elite. So yes, I guess I do see him as a facilitator of "right wing wackos." Friedman himself I see has an academic of great intelligence and analytical skill who none the less targeted his gun at the wrong target, much like a certain idiot VP.

Now on the your link. Yes I have read the report but what point were you trying to make by posting a link to it? Can you expand on the link besides posting it cryptically?


Skeletor,

Can you expand upon what you are talking about perhaps using some form of logical connection between your arguments? You have leapt from the AMA to foreign doctors [Oooooooh - is that a NIMBY argument], to quality vs. quantity to ND licensing. If there is any connection here you have not presented it.

I would like to understand what you are trying to say, but at this time, you have made that impossible. Please fill in the blanks. Feel free to use links, evidence, and logic.

Anonymous said...

amadeus,

If you bothered to read Milton's essay, you would understand the context for my comments. Please refrain from further negative rants untill you read that essay.

Wolfgang said...

Skeleto,

You said "If you bothered to read Milton's essay, you would understand the context for my comments. Please refrain from further negative rants untill you read that essay."

I have taken your advice, reread Milton's essay which I found to be horribly out of date considering the current regulatory environment and event happening within the AMA and especially their student group [very interesting stuff happening there], and my comments.

I must admit that I owe you an apology for the tone of my comments, but I will also admit that I do not think that your point was adequately made.

Are you saying that regulation of ND's is solely about quality control and if so in which way do you see Milton's essay supporting or refuting this stand?

I was very rude in my comments to you and I should have worded them with more grace, however upon rereading them I still see them primarily as an inquiry, however rude, and not a rant.

A rant is more like this. [written in jest]. You sir, are an asshat who doesn't know what he is talking about. Come out of brownspace and look around. Uncle Milton ate babies for breakfast so we can't take anything he said at face value. And let's talk about your mother......

Cheers,

Wolfgang

Anonymous said...

Rumor has it that the primary author of this essay is the one true Uncle Miltie, Milton Berle.
Milton Berle and Milton Friedman were very fond of each other and often collaborated on scholarly papers, as well as comic routines.
They were known as the "biggest" comedian and economist, respectively, of their time.

Contributors

What is the source of 'Big Money' behind the ND Registration Bill?